Zoning

Cities adopt a range of zoning and other policies that prevent density and the environmental and economic benefits that density provides. Zoning is a major contributor in high housing costs 1, and by preventing people from being able to move to highly productive cities, zoning restrictions are estimated to cost the American economy from $400 billion to $1.7 trillion per year 2, 3, 4.

The main classes of zoning restrictions--unit size, parking requirements, lot size, and height rules--should be subjected to periodic cost-benefit audit. In some cases there may be justification for retaining the rules, such as management of traffic 5, but cities should periodically reanalyze their rules.

Zoning Impact Overview

There is a wide range of policies that cities adopt that affect development patterns. We compare the land, energy, and greenhouse gas impacts of four of the major policies.

The image: "Zoning Costs.svg" cannot be found!

Comparison of the energy and land use impacts of four zoning policies, shown per unit affected. The rules are a minimum lot requirement of half an acre for single family homes, when otherwise a median lot would be used; a parking minimum that requires 0.5 more parking spaces per unit than necessary for a walk-up apartment; a minimum unit size that causes a building of studio apartments to be built instead of an single room occupancy building; and a height limit that requires a six story apartment building when the market would otherwise supply 12 stories. For the latter three scenarios, all people displaced by zoning instead live in median lot detached homes. Source and calculation details are below.

Zoning regulations impose considerable cost on homebuyers and the economy.

The image: "zoning_tax.svg" cannot be found!

The authors estimate a "zoning tax" as the difference between the sale price of a property and construction cost. Absent regulation that constricts supply, the two should be equal. In Cincinnati, sale prices are below construction costs, so no zoning tax is estimated. Source: 6.

Property Rights

Zoning attempts to balance two concerns in urban development: the need and economic value of new develop with the external costs of development, including traffic congestion. In principle, if property rights are fully delineated, then property owners should be able to negotiate an economically efficient system of development 7. In practice, transaction costs associated with negotiation among many, even thousands, of property owners in intractably complicated 8.

Problem:
Restricted Housing Supply
Solution:
Street-Level Zoning

Unit Size

Most cities place severe restrictions or outright bans 9 on the construction of small housing units, such as microapartments (typically less than 300 square feet) or single-room occupancy units. Allowing small units can create affordable options for singles that would otherwise not be available, as well as take pressure off the market for larger units. In cities with a high cost of living, there is strong evidence for unmet demand for small units 10.

The following shows how a given building with 67,100 gross square feet can accommodate more people through small unit sizes.

The image: "compact_housing2.svg" cannot be found!

Allowing smaller units can increase the housing stock in a given building envelope. Source: Stern and Yager 11.

Problem:
Housing Affordability
Solution:
Zoning Should Allow for Smaller Housing Units

Parking Minimum

Most cities require new developments to provide parking. These requirements often exceed the actual need for parking, adding to the cost of new development and consuming space that could otherwise be used more productively.

The image: "Annual Parking Cost.svg" cannot be found!

Cost of providing parking. Source: Litman 12.

The cost of excessive parking spaces is borne by the developer, who must in turn pass it on to the renters, homebuyers, or businesses. Including access roads, one acre holds 125 parking space 12, preventing the construction of 5 single family homes with median lot size, 22 walk-up apartment units, or 72 midrise apartment units. The reduction in the housing stock raises the cost of living throughout the city 13.

Problem:
Cost From Mandated Parking
Solution:
Remove Parking Minimums
Problem:
Costs of Free Parking
Solution:
End Public-Provided Free Parking - U.S.

Density Restrictions

Cities often require a minimum lot size for new single-family homes. These rules lower population density and increase the cost of housing. In the Greater Boston Area, for instance, an increase of the minimum lot requirement by a quarter acre causes an estimated 10% decrease in the housing supply and 3.3% increase in price 14. By lowering population density below what it would otherwise be, minimum lot size regulations contribute to urban sprawl and resulting environmental costs, such as traffic congestion and land use impacts 15. In Connecticut, homes in towns with the largest lots are associated with 36.1% more transportation CO2 emissions and 18.3% housing emissions than homes in the other towns 16. The reduction of supply in one town raises prices in neighboring towns 17.

Similarly, restrictions on the height of buildings, or on the floor-area ratio (the ratio between the total building floor space and the area of the lot) reduce a city's supply of valuable floor space that is close to the urban core.

Problem:
Cost of Density Restrictions
Solution:
Loosen Floor-Area Ratio Rules
Problem:
Cost of Density Restrictions
Solution:
Loosen Minimum Lot Size Rules

References

  1. Glaeser, E., Gyourko, J. "The Impact of Zoning on Housing Affordability". March 2002.

  2. Glaeser, E., Gyourko, J. "The Economic Implications of Housing Supply". Journal of Economic Perspectives 32(1), pp. 3-30. Winter 2018.

  3. Herkenhoff, K., Ohanian, L., Prescott, E. "Tarnishing the Golden and Empire States: Land-Use Restrictions and the U.S. Economic Slowdown". Journal of Monetary Economics 93, pp. 89-109. January 2018.

  4. Hsieh, C. and Moretti, E. "Housing Constraints and Spatial Misallocation". NBER Working Paper No. 21154. May 2017.

  5. Terasaki, T. "The Impact of Raising the Maximum Floor Area Ratio on Commuting Congestion". Economic & Industrial Research Department, Development Bank of Japan. April 2005.

  6. Gyourko, J., Krimmel, J. "The Impact of Local Residential Land Use Restrictions on Land Values Across and Within Single Family Housing Markets". National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 28993. July 2021.

  7. Coase, R. H. "The Problem of Social Cost". The Journal of Law and Economics 3, pp. 87-137. October 1960.

  8. Rhoads, T. A., Shogren, J. F. "On Coasean bargaining with transaction costs". Applied Economics Letters 6(12). 1999.

  9. Gabbe, C. J. "Looking through the lens of size: Land use regulations and micro-apartments in San Francisco". Cityscape 17(2). 2015.

  10. Urban Land Institute. "The Macro View on Micro Units". 2014.

  11. Stern, E., Yager, J. "21st Century SROs: Can Small Housing Units Help Meet the Need for Affordable Housing in New York City?". NYU Furman Center. February 2018.

  12. Litman, T. "Parking Requirement Impacts on Housing Affordability". Victoria Transport Policy Institute. August 2016. 2

  13. Andersson, M., Mandell, S., Thörn, H., Gomér, Y. "The effect of minimum parking requirements on the housing stock". Transport Policy 49, pp. 206-215. July 2016.

  14. Glaeser, E., Schuetz, J., Ward, B. "How large lot zoning and other town regulations are driving up home prices". CommonWealth Magazine. January 2006.

  15. Boudreaux, P. "Lotting Large: The Phenomenon of Minimum Lot Size Laws". Maine Law Review 68(1). January 2016.

  16. Blanco, K., Bronin, S. "Small Lots in Smart Places: A Right-Sized Solution for CT". DesegregateCT, Regional Plan Association. 2022.

  17. Zabel, J., Dalton, M. "The impact of minimum lot size regulations on house prices in Eastern Massachusetts". Regional Science and Urban Economics 41(6), pp. 571-583. November 2011.